Commentary of the EU Microsoft Antitrust Case

 

by Nicholas Economides

Stern School of Business, NYU,

email: economides@stern.nyu.edu

NET Institute (www.NETInst.org)

Visiting UC Berkeley/Haas

 

On Sept. 17, 2007, EU’s antitrust decision of 2004 on Microsoft was upheld on appeal almost in its entirety.  The EU case had two parts: one on the inclusion of Windows Media Player (“WMP”) in Windows, and one on the interoperability of Windows clients with Sun servers.  The consequences are significant both for Microsoft and the computing industry. 

 

On media players, the Commission forced Microsoft to sell in Europe “Windows-N,” a version of Windows without WMP.  Microsoft complied.  Windows-N sales were less than 1% of Windows sales.  It is evident that consumers and computer manufacturers do not want an operating system with less functionality.  However, with its decision upheld, the Commission can now force any dominant firm (and remember that dominance can be established at much lower market shares in the EU than the US) to sell products with functionality or components removed from them. 

 

Is the EU requirement likely to make a difference?  The marketplace said no.  And, while the EU battled Microsoft on media players for nine (!) years at the behest of Real Networks, Adobe’s Flash emerged as the dominant PC video player and Apple grabbed the lion’s share in the online song download market with a proprietary format.  The Commission’s indirect “indirect network effects theory” (that the ubiquity of distribution of WMP through Windows will result in content providers coding content only for WMP and this will reinforce the WMP market share) has been proven completely irrelevant by the marketplace. 

 

So, both the anti-competitive network effects theory and the imposed remedy have been proven irrelevant by the marketplace.  What remains?  Has there been any benefit to consumers by the Commission’s action?  The typical consumer receives the WMP with a new Windows computer and then downloads and tries a few other media players.  It takes a few minutes to download and install them – an insignificant consumers’ surplus loss.  It is hard to imagine that this insignificant loss drove this antitrust case.  Even though the loss is small, is it remedied by the EU’s approach?  Not at all.  Windows-N did not sell.  And this was fortunate for consumers!  If Windows-N were a success, consumers who bought it would have been deprived of even the knowledge that media players existed!  In contrast, the USDOJ-Microsoft consent decree allows key Microsoft middleware (such as WMP and Internet Explorer) to be in Windows but gives the choice to both the computer manufacturer and the consumer to select the default media player, Internet browser, etc.  Thus, the US consent decree gives the consumers choice while the EU rule deprives them of choice.

 

More generally, software development has progressed with constant additions to functionality of existing software.  This is true across the whole software sector.  The Commission’s approach was to “freeze” Windows (or any dominant firm’s product) and force the dominant firm to sell the “frozen” version side-by-side with the expanded functionality version.  The marketplace rejects the frozen version, so this rule hardly remedies anything.  In the US, the eight States that did not sign the consent decree went one step further in their proposed remedy: they required Microsoft to sell a frozen version of Windows and set a specific price difference between the full and the frozen versions.  Judge Kollar-Kotelly correctly rejected this approach as overly regulatory: the court was asked to guess what the marketplace would pay for each new feature of Windows – a judicial nightmare.

 

On interoperability, the Commission imposed the requirement on Microsoft to license communications protocols between Windows clients and non-Windows servers.  Interoperability defines the ability of two products to work together.  In software, there can be varying degrees of interoperability.  Some interoperability can be guaranteed by the interface between the components.  But full interoperability between say a Sun server and a Windows client requires the understanding of exactly how internal functions in the Windows client work.  Requiring disclosure of the interface between products is one thing; requiring disclosure of the internal functions of a product (since this may be the only way to reach full interoperability) is much more onerous.  By requiring full disclosure at a nominal price, the EU decision in effect reduces the value of intellectual property for dominant firms.  Additionally, in the particular case, full understanding of internal Windows functions is valuable to Sun beyond interoperability.  To the extent that Windows clients and servers have similar technology, full disclosure allows Sun to see how the Windows server works.  That is, the Commission’s vertical remedy gives an advantage to Sun in horizontal competition. 

 

The EU case outcome showed a significant divergence in antitrust standards between the EU and the US.  Almost all observers agree that, if the EU case were tried in the US, it would not result in liability for Microsoft.  The differences in antitrust standards (and the list can easily include a number of other countries such as Japan and Korea) imply that global companies need to comply with the most strict antitrust standards, wherever they may be, and however they may evolve.  And, their competitors can peddle their potential antitrust disputes to competition authorities world-wide, and see which one might be willing to do the heavy lifting of pursuing their case.  Most people complain that lawyers (and their consultants) are expensive.  But compared to the cost of investing in innovation or cutting prices, lawyers are cheap.  And we are still in the beginning of the next cycle of antitrust litigation in the high technology sector.